Wednesday, April 1, 2015

A Challenge to Piketty's "Capital"

Even though we aren't reading Piketty until later in the quarter I thought this was an interesting article from The Economist (article link here). Professor McKinney mentioned that Piketty's book "Capital in the 21st Century" has become incredibly popular but that there are a number of people that disagree with his argument. 

In his book, Piketty claims "that over the long run the rate on return of wealth exceeds economic growth: a dynamic summed up in the equation r>g. Over time, this relationship increases inequality as the share of national income going to those who own capital (the rich) rises, while the portion going to labour (everyone else) falls. He also argues that the return on capital in recent history has been remarkably stable, even as economic growth has fallen, and that this trend will continue in the future." 

Many people have made counter arguments to Piketty's claims but most recently a graduate student at MIT presented a paper at the Brookings Papers on Economic Activity (an abstract can be found here) and some believe this to be one of the most substantial arguments against Piketty's ideas presented in "Capital". 

The graduate student, Matthew Rognlie, has three major criticisms according to The Economist. 

  1. "First, he argues that the rate of return from capital probably declines over the long run, rather than remaining high as Mr Piketty suggests, due to the law of diminishing marginal returns. Modern forms of capital, such as software, depreciate faster in value than equipment did in the past: a giant metal press might have a working life of decades while a new piece of database-management software will be obsolete in a few years at most."  
  2. "Second, Mr Rognlie’s research suggests that Mr Piketty has overestimated how high the returns on wealth are likely to be in the future. These should also decline over time, he reckons, unless it is very easy for the economy to substitute capital (like robots) for workers."
  3. "Third, Mr Rognlie finds that the growing share of national income deriving from capital income has not been distributed equally across all sectors. The return on non-housing wealth, in fact, has been remarkably stable since 1970. Instead, surging house prices are almost entirely responsible for growing returns on capital."
I thought it was very interesting how the basics of Rognlie's argument was centered around topics that we have learned in prior classes such as the law if diminishing marginal returns and the ability to substitute capital for labor. 

It should be noted that Mr. Rognlie is not without critics. Some claim that he "appears to underestimate the role changing technology plays in widening inequality". Rognlie's arguments will be something to keep in mind when we read Piketty! 

4 comments:

  1. This comment has been removed by the author.

    ReplyDelete
  2. This is very interesting. It may be true that modern capital such as software eventually becomes obsolete, but does it really depreciate in value? There are countless business applications/software that have been around for years yet are still used by the world's biggest corporations. Take Microsoft SQL/office as an example. In today's corporations, Microsoft has become an essential tool to use for communication, creating documents, storing data, etc. It is hard to say that software depreciates in value since it is constantly evolving and updating in order to provide a better user experience. Yes, there are some software such as SAP (a widely used accounting application) that are slowly becoming obsolete as new start-ups try to compete by offering free services.

    I also agree that it is definitely interesting to that Rognlie, used core principles of economics to support his counter argument. However, I think it is important to note that principles alone cannot explain the growth of capitalism. For example, core economic theories have a hard time explaining to explosive growth of today's tech industry. There are start-ups popping up each and every day around the world. Some of these early staged start-ups go on to raise insane amounts of capital and have billion dollar valuations yet they lack a revenue-generating business model. Snapchat would be a prime example in its early investing rounds of capital.

    ReplyDelete
  3. Highly captivating. Reading Piketty would definitely help, however, from first glance I agree more with Piketty than with Rognlie. The main reason for this is that I've only seen the law of diminishing marginal returns (LDMR) when applied to production. When applied to the capital markets (and perhaps real estate markets), the law seemingly breaks down in my mind, while compound interest takes over. Cetaris paribus, the more one invests in capital markets, the more they should be receiving in the form of capital appreciation and/or dividends, which compound over time.

    Perhaps, however, the LDMR has a very high threshold for capital markets, and mainly applies to extremely wealthy individuals and organizations, as cash heavy mutual funds and corporations struggle immensely to realize returns higher than the risk free rate on their investments.

    ReplyDelete
  4. I agree with Phil that this is an interesting article. However, I agree with the other economist that Rognlie underestimates the impact of changing technology has on increasing the inequality gap. The rapid rate of globalization today has increased international trade. As a result, the capital-intensive countries will specialize in good industries that are capital-intensive since those good industries have a comparative advantage compared to other trading nations. This increase in demand for capital-intensive goods will lead to an increase in the real wage of capital-rich owners, while labor-rich owners will experience a decrease in real wage. (This is known as the Hecksher-Ohlin Theorem and is similarly applied to labor-rich countries.) As a result the country will become more specialized in producing goods that utilize the abundant resource (capital in this example). Even though countries specialize more in producing goods with a comparative advantage, countries can never fully specialize when they have more than one production factor (e.g. capital, labor, land, etc.); that is, some laborers will still remain in the industries that don’t have a comparative advantage. Those laborers that remain are workers that are highly skilled, while the lower-skilled are unemployed. In order to achieve high skills, a higher level of education is required. Sadly, level of education is correlated to level of wealth/income. Overall, advancements in technology cause the lower-skilled from (usually) socioeconomic backgrounds that are below average to suffer while the highly-skilled and industries intensive with a country’s abundant resources to benefit.
    Here is an interesting link from the New York Times that discussed the impact of technological advancements on income inequality: http://www.nytimes.com/2013/12/02/world/europe/measuring-the-wealth-effect-in-education.html

    ReplyDelete